Comment by JumpCrisscross
5 days ago
> because this doesn’t magically solve the housing crisis
It does. Twenty thousand units represent about 5% of Denver's housing stock [1]. Commit to adding this many units to the housing stock every year for the next 10 years and you'll have solved the housing crisis. (You'll probably need to bail out recent homebuyers, who will be permanently underwater, but that's a separate issue.)
[1] http://censusreporter.org/profiles/16000US0820000-denver-co/
> You'll probably need to bail out recent homebuyers, who will be permanently underwater
If you buy a house for $400k, and suddenly it is worth $300k, you don't need to be "bailed out" for your purchase decision. You should have been certain that the house was worth $400k to you at the time of purchase. Otherwise you're a speculator, and we shouldn't be bailing out speculators.
It's called buyer's remorse. We accept it when it's a car or a TV, but suddenly when it's a house we're supposed to give massive government support to correct the buyer's mistake?
Yeah, pretty sure a government won’t bail me out if I invested in a stock so much that it would crush me if the stock went down. If buying a house is an investment and not for living, then it should be treated like it is.
> pretty sure a government won’t bail me out if I invested in a stock
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Greenspan_put
More pointedly, you're not in a position to block equity capital markets reforms in the way homeowners are in respect of housing reform.
7 replies →
people call buying a house to live in an investment but that's because they don't know the technical term is a "hedge"
so you know: most localities do treat the house you live in very differently from a tax perspective than they do any additional properties you might have, because everyone is born short housing, until they own 1 place to live.
so yes, the proposed bailouts up thread would be for people who bought a house because they didn't want to be short housing; a hedge, not an investment.
also if the house has hedges then your hedges are a hedge. I'll see myself out
6 replies →
It isn't, though. Housing is a basic human need; investing in the stock market is not.
Whether a house is worth $400k or $300k is, sometimes, a choice the government makes.
It isn't always, but sometimes it is. Through regulations, through monetary policy, through other policies.
Now if the government decides that you, you personally, standardUser, are going to lose $100k, I don't think the government should bail you out. It's called "moral hazard". You lost $100k. Deal with it.
If the government decides that I, me personally, am going to lost $100k, I would say that I am old and I vote in every single election, and despite my failing memory, I will remember that lost $100k until the day I die and no politician who voted for that will ever get my vote again. I will remember who did that to me.
> It isn't always, but sometimes it is.
I think it always is, frankly. The price of pretty much every single house in the US[0] is a function of decades of government housing policy. And I don't think it's particularly fair to say, "oopsie, our housing policy since before you were born was kinda bad, we're going to fix it right now, but it's going to put you underwater on your mortgage... sorry, but you'll have to just deal with it".
[0] Sure, maybe this isn't the case for an off-the-grid cabin out in the woods, far from any town, but that describes a teeny tiny portion of the housing stock.
As someone that's bought their first house in the last few years, it's hard not to take offense.
A car or a TV are much smaller investments relative to a house. Over a decade of savings is tied up in my home. If the ass drops out of the market, myself, and others like me, who have broken into the market without assistance at the peak of housing prices will be virtually permanently financially set back. And to call buying a house around this time a mistake is crazy. I would be as much a speculator if I continued to rent and pay someone else's mortgage, hoping that prices dropped so I could get a good deal. It's a home and this attitude of treating homes as investments or mere purchases is why we're in this mess in the first place.
How is it fair to compare buying a house to buying a TV? One costs 500$ and the other costs 500k plus ongoing costs like repairs and taxes. Not saying you’re wrong, just that the comparison isn’t apt
Because if you're buying a house for a house, then it (mostly, generally¹) doesn't matter that the housing market has moved downwards and you'll be underwater until you pay down a bit on the house. You still have a house! So long as you can afford the mortgage — something you should have already planned for given you bought the house — you can still afford it. You might have remorse at having paid +$100k right before the market moved, but that's what the parent is saying: that's buyer's remorse, that is speculating on the price, when instead, you should be saying "am I willing (and financially able) to trade $400k for a home to live in?"
(¹I don't want to get too much into the sidetrack that is "but if you're underwater you could lose your home" — yes… that's possible. The example here is a 20% fall in prices — which would be astounding to those of us wanting a home, the thing of dreams — but you put 20% in the down payment, so a single mortgage payment & you're no longer underwater. In reality, the price drop (in rent, but let's work with what we got) was 3.7%. (Don't get me wrong, I'd take that too, as a renter.))
5 replies →
Some loans require PMI if your outstanding balance is larger than the current value. PMI is very expensive and, unlike a TV or car, you might be forced to give up your house because it devalued too far and you can no longer afford mortgage and PMI.
I'm not saying we shouldn't make housing affordable, but it's worth considering the impact for everyone.
I don't think lenders have any ability to retroactively require PMI; certainly no mortgage I've ever signed permitted this.
1 reply →
Isn't that something regulation (of mortgages) solves way better than forever banning decrease in housing costs?
2 replies →
> If you buy a house for $400k, and suddenly it is worth $300k, you don't need to be "bailed out" for your purchase decision. You should have been certain that the house was worth $400k to you at the time of purchase. Otherwise you're a speculator, and we shouldn't be bailing out speculators.
Isn't that missing the forest for the trees? There's an all-out class war between the haves and the have-nots. If it controls supply like a cartel, and if it pursues rent-seeking like a cartel, then maybe the real estate moguls and speculators that treat everything like an investment instrument should be held accountable and liable.
You never know what your house or apartment or condo is worth, even to you. Maybe you can afford $400k barely, but you'll be hugely squeezed. Or maybe you'd get a bigger place if prices had dropped for your family size.
You hope conditions won't change. You can look at the current market trends to try to value it. But things will change in the next few years probably. You can guess, but you'll never "know with pretty good accuracy". The economy can go down, interest rates can change, major employers can come and go, there can be an earthquake or cancerous ground discovered there.
This is the rat race. You are competing with all the other humans around you in the same playspace of reality.
A mortgage is a loan that gives you money you don't have (yet). If you are spending money you don't have, do it wisely or suffer the consequences.
I think no special treatment. Everyone else in the same space has the same rules/uncertainty as every argument you offered.
4 replies →
Take out an insurance policy then, not my problem
But, the convention in the US is that people see their houses as a form of savings. Realistically, we should account for that.
Also, if continuing the building ends up requiring some policy change (supported by changing laws and regulations)… it seems reasonable to protect normal people, doing normal things, from massive financial chaos that is explicitly caused by the government changing policies on them. At least for people actually using the houses as intended, that is, living in them.
>But, the convention in the US is that people see their houses as a form of savings. Realistically, we should account for that.
Why? If it makes society as a whole much poorer.
The convention is fairly recent and the cause of enormous problems.
9 replies →
> But, the convention in the US is that people see their houses as a form of savings.
And that is a big part of the problem. You cannot have it both ways, if housing is an investment, it will eventually lead to poorer outcomes for anybody that needs a house and does not inherit one.
1 reply →
If we go to a place where homes cost $400k then we're all buying at $400k, regardless of whether people understand speculation or markets. Once you allow enough people with deep pockets to do speculation or price arbitrage... then we're all paying it.
It's not that we shouldn't desire cheaper homes, but we should realize that people who paid $400k are largely not speculators. They bought what the market was willing to offer.
>It's called buyer's remorse. We accept it when it's a car or a TV, but suddenly when it's a house we're supposed to give massive government support to correct the buyer's mistake?
The difference is order of magnitude as proportion of net worth and the necessity of the purchase.
And it's not like the actual value has decreased. You still own the same house. It's the same size, location, build quality... That's the value of the house to you. If you're not currently buying a house, the price of a house should be irrelevant to you.
But the price you were strong armed into paying is more than the value of that stuff, and you only begrudgingly accepted the price that included a large speculative component, because you saw that the government has been guaranteeing that the speculative component only goes up.
If the government passed subsidy laws or building requirements that caused your loss, then you might expect compensation. Did you disagree with bailing out small businesses shuttered during COVID and their furloughed employees? Same principle.
Small businesses being bailed out was presumably because of liquidity issues.
Being underwater does not cause a liquidity issue.
But the buyer probably didn't think it was actually worth $400k intrinsically. They were bullied into paying $400k because (1) they need a house no matter what and (2) at least the government guarantees that there will be a bigger sucker down the line who will pay $500k.
It's the government's fault that this bigger-fool game even exists, because the buck always stops there. They might want to consider compensating people for the misery they caused.
We (government) does debt forgiveness all the time. For very practical reasons. Can't some of the cheddar be redirected from the 0.1% to the rest of us?
A $400k home is probably a starter home. Owners are probably a young couple (millennials). They probably want to have kids.
Forgiving 100k of their debt means they (and their kids) will have a fair chance at success. Earning more money. Saving more. Paying more taxes (over their life times).
While at the end of the day I don’t think people should be bailed out, I don’t agree that everyone who over paid is a speculator. Many people are just wanting to own their own home. The market has been crazy for the last 5 years. Many people are just buying to own not to flip it for a huge profit. So when a new home owner buys something and suddenly the value drops $100k and the bank wants the money I do feel slightly sorry for them.
For the person who ownes multiple houses and buys simply to rent and flip a profit well I have very little sympathy for them. They are the true speculators.
> So when a new home owner buys something and suddenly the value drops $100k and the bank wants the money
That's not how mortgages work (in the US, anyway). If the value drops, nothing happens, you still have the same house and same mortgage.
I've been underwater twice, in the same house, as prices go up and down over the years. As long as you still like the house and want to continue living there (I did), being underwater doesn't mean anything.
2 replies →
> So when a new home owner buys something and suddenly the value drops $100k and the bank wants the money I do feel slightly sorry for them.
I feel a little sorry for them but they are not missing the money total of "the whole house". They can sell the house, have a shitty $100k debt, a tale of woe, and hopefully a better idea of how to go about spending money they didn't have.
I feel there are too many people who "borrow as much as they can for the best house they can get" rather than being sensible about their money and using a mortgage as a hedge against paying rent and future rent raises. Some of them make it, some of them don't.
2 replies →
> So when a new home owner buys something and suddenly the value drops $100k and the bank wants the money I do feel slightly sorry for them.
I don’t understand this point. If you’re paying the mortgage, the bank dgaf. Is there some sort of margin call a bank can claim on a house that is worth less than it was when it was purchased?
Don’t you just pay the mortgage you agreed to pay the bank?
Well those people vote. Home ownership rate is 65%. Home owners I believe are more likely to vote than renters. So yeah your proposition is not feasible
I agree in principle that we shouldn't be bailing people out for the consequences of making purchases with their eyes open, but if something like this happened, a lot of people would be mad. And I get it.
The problem in this eventuality is mobility: if you buy a house for $400k, live there for, say, 5 years and the resale value of your house is at $300k, that's going to be a big problem if you have (or just want) to move. If you sell at $300k, you'll have about $50k left over (after repaying the bank) for a down payment on your new house, which means you can only afford a $250k house, which may well not meet your needs.
If someone is planning to live in that house long enough such that when they do want to sell it, they can move to a new place that meets their needs, at a price they can still afford, sure, great. We shouldn't be bailing those people out.
> You should have been certain that the house was worth $400k to you at the time of purchase. Otherwise you're a speculator, and we shouldn't be bailing out speculators.
That's absurd. Aside from people who buy too much house ('00s, anyone?) and regret it later, people pay the price they have to pay for the amount of space and location they believe they need. Most people -- very understandably -- don't know the dynamics of the housing market to the point that they'd be able to predict that their resale value might go down by 25% at some point in the future, because, historically, that's just not what home prices do. (And don't parrot the "past performance is no guarantee of the future" crap... yes, true, so what. Most people unfortunately can't plan their lives around that.)
These people aren't speculators... speculators are buying to flip, or to hold and resell, as investment properties. These are just regular folks who need a place to live and have -- regardless of prudence or correctness -- bought into the idea that owning their home is the next life stage, a proof of success and well-being. Calling people like that speculators shows a severe lack of understanding and empathy.
> It's called buyer's remorse. We accept it when it's a car or a TV, but suddenly when it's a house...
A car or a TV costs nowhere near as much as a house. Losing a car or a TV is not going to make someone homeless. Housing is a basic need, and housing security is essential in a healthy society. (Granted, in many places in the US, losing your car can lead to financial ruin as well, sadly, considering how crucial a car can be to many people for basic things like getting to work.)
> Losing a car or a TV is not going to make someone homeless.
Your house losing 100k$ in value isn't going to make you homeless either (quite the opposite actually). If you buy a house and it depreciates, so what?
Not to mention if everyone's house depreciates, your new house is cheaper to buy. You lose _nothing_, except imaginary dollar values.
> Calling people like that speculators shows a severe lack of understanding and empathy.
I don't know what you call preventing young people from buying, or even renting, at affordable prices so 'people like that' don't have a possibility of losing some money, but you sure as fuck don't call it empathy either.
1 reply →
> If you buy a house for $400k, and suddenly it is worth $300k, you don't need to be "bailed out" for your purchase decision. You should have been certain that the house was worth $400k to you at the time of purchase.
I think it's pretty normal for rational purchasers to consider the resale value of something that they purchase, and hand-waving that away doesn't make for a very serious argument.
I think it's pretty normal for resale to be less than purchase price. Considering it is important!
Making any guarantees as to the future worth of these items is craziness.
2 replies →
Very rarely does the value of a purchase increase over time. Literally the only examples I can come up with are things that are very old and rare, or a house.
Viewing a home as some kind of investment vehicle is everything wrong with the housing market today. It’s so wrong it makes my head spin.
> If you buy a house for $400k, and suddenly it is worth $300k, you don't need to be "bailed out" for your purchase decision...we shouldn't be bailing out speeculators
When the speculators vote, yes, you need to bail out the speculators.
> It's called buyer's remorse
It's called building consensus. At the end of the day, if it costs making homeowners whole to gain their buy in to solve the housing crisis, that's money well spent.
I'm not saying what I'm proposing is fair or even palatable. But it's functional. If solving the housing crisis is more important than aesthetics, it's a good move.
I agree there are political considerations, but we are talking about a scenario where the only damage done is that the buyer must continue to live in the home they purchased at the price they purchased it for, and where the recipient of government benefits is a household capable of purchasing a house, presumably at the height of the market. Is a tax dollar better spent placating grumpy homeowners who already have a place to live they can afford, or by more directly building more housing and infrastructure?
10 replies →
House owners are just going to vote for harsher impediments to building.
> It does. Twenty thousand units represent about 5% of Denver's housing stock [1]. Commit to adding this many units to the housing stock every year for the next 10 years and you'll have solved the housing crisis. (You'll probably need to bail out recent homebuyers, who will be permanently underwater, but that's a separate issue.)
That is only if you believe that more capacity does not induce more demand, which really isn't true as long as the city remains popular for jobs/climate/nature/etc.... People not moving to Denver because the rent is too high will decide to move to Denver if rents decrease (and the demand they add will cause rents to increase, wash/rinse/repeat until an equilibrium is reached). You also have cases where a city becomes even more attractive because of growing density alone (NYC, Hong Kong, Tokyo).
This argument always comes up when discussing a specific place.
"Everyone would move to ________ because it is the best place in the spiral arm of the Milky Way", where ________ is Boulder, Bend, Austin, Portland, San Francisco, Santa Barbara, Hawai'i, Santa Fe, etc.... etc....
It cannot be true for all of them. So they all need to build and people will figure out where they actually want to live.
Bozeman, Montana, a small city of 50K people, is seeing falling rents because they built a lot of housing:
https://montanafreepress.org/2025/06/23/has-bozemans-rental-...
And it's very much the kind of small place where "everyone wants to live there".
If everyone could live where they wanted to live, then ya, why wouldn't everyone want to live in the best cities?
If you have fixed demand, then you can definitely "build" your way out of a housing crisis. Bozeman, for example, doesn't have many jobs, so you can't really live there if you don't bring your own money. A big city like Seattle or Denver... they have lots of jobs, so they will grow at least to the point that all those jobs have people working them...but then a city like that attracts even more jobs (the way cities work since they concentrate talent, which attracts more businesses looking for that talent), more people, it could grow from a million people to 10 or 20 million easily.
> And it's very much the kind of small place where "everyone wants to live there".
MT is a bad place if you need to work for a living: high housing prices, jobs don't pay very well if you can find them at all. My mom moved to Helena in the late 90s and found that out first hand. If WFH took off as expected, then you definitely could make a good life in Bozeman or Missoula or Butte, but alas, the opposite happened and we regressed greatly.
11 replies →
Induced demand can only function if there's a scarcity to begin with, and it's premised on increased supply increasing affordability (that's the mechanism by which it works), but these axiomatic derivations don't matter because we have case studies (in MN, in TX, and now CO, a story we're literally commenting on). Empirical observations win.
> Induced demand can only function if there's a scarcity to begin with, and it's premised on increased supply increasing affordability (that's the mechanism by which it works)
I don't think that's how the theory is supposed to work. It's more along the lines of, if you build more housing in a place then more people live there and then the higher population density can sustain more shops and jobs, and then people want to live near shops and jobs so the local demand increases.
There are two reasons the theory doesn't actually mean that you can't solve the problem with more housing.
The first is, the effect isn't infinite. As the reductio, if the entire New York Metro area had the population density of Manhattan, it would house 450M people, which is more than the entire US population. So you can build more housing than you have people to move into it even if that would literally cause the entire national population to move to the same place, and of course building that much housing in one place wouldn't cause literally everyone to move there anyway, so the amount you need in practice is far less than that.
And the second is, it's a local effect that comes from net migration. If you build more housing in Denver and that causes people to want to move from Austin to Denver, even if you don't build enough to overcome that in Denver itself, you'd still be lowering housing costs in Austin. And if you're simultaneously building new housing everywhere then there is no net migration and therefore no induced demand anywhere.
1 reply →
This Colorado story includes construction already slowing so why should we be convinced this is the start of a downward trend toward affordability vs a corrective blip after the Covid-era remote work migration trend?
Affordability and desirability are always going to be in constant tension, and any given change - including construction - can tip things more one way than the other. The long-term affordability trends are poor even in states like Texas - is that purely because of construction? No, it also has to do with policies like trying to poach established businesses from other states and importing wealth and high salaried individuals. But it shows that development is no panacea and that even in areas with more open land to build more new construction on there are still powerful trends in the US towards sprawl, low-to-medium density, and rising cost of living. Without explicit intervention like subsidies or direct government construction development will slow - focusing on higher-ROI units for the same spend vs pure unit count - as developers worry more about not being able to command the per-unit price they want if they were to aim for quantity.
> Induced demand can only function if there's a scarcity to begin with
I don't believe this is true, assuming scarcity = shortage. Ad absurdum, if Denver overbuilt such that one could pick up a parcel for a song, you'd see opportunistic demand where there previously was none.
3 replies →
That's why you have to allow large-scale building everywhere. Then the market will find its own level.
The inverse of this situation is that everyone lives somewhere they consider unpleasant because the rent is affordable there.
The megacities you mention are enormously economically productive per capita. All sorts of efficiencies pop up when a huge number of people live near one another.
> The megacities you mention are enormously economically productive per capita. All sorts of efficiencies pop up when a huge number of people live near one another.
It isn't a bad thing. NYC and Hong Kong are nice cities, they should exist. But don't expect housing prices to fall because you add more density if demand isn't fixed, the opposite often happens instead (people want to live in megacities even though housing costs are high). And that isn't really a bad thing, like gentrifying a blighted neighborhood will drive up housing prices as well.
> only if you believe that more capacity does not induce more demand
No, it doesn't. What you're describing is elasticity. It's a well-studed concept, and means that a 5% increase in supply will probably reduce prices by less than 4.8%.
(An interesting side effect of a government committing to a zero real-price increase housing strategy is it eliminates whole categories of speculative demand. I wouldn't count on this for policy effects. But it's another feather in the cap for pro-housing policy.)
Giving significantly more people a way to live a lifestyle they seek, while holding the cost of housing flat -- if thats the worst case outcome, that seems totally fine, and arguably a better solution than trying to crash the cost of housing.
I would imagine for most people, this is what "solving the housing crisis" means
Except that all the folks that left Austin to move to Denver makes the houses prices in Austin drop.
Now the folks in Denver who hadn't considered Austin due to high rates can move there and reduce the costs in Denver again.
A 5% increase in supply annually indefinitely would crash the housing market there, induced demand be damned. To put it in perspective, a metro area growing at 2% is killing it, the highest growth rate is Austin at 3%. Denver only grows at less than 1%.
Cheaper homes may induce demand, they won't induce a 5% growth rate.
> A 5% increase in supply annually indefinitely would crash the housing market there
Only if population is held constant.
Housing supply is inelastic, but housing demand is somewhat elastic. As seen in Denver, an increase in housing supply would decrease prices. But those lower prices will increase demand from people that want to live in Denver but previously couldn’t afford it.
1 reply →
You keep building until supply meets demand, regardless of what that demand is or where it comes from.
We don't have an infinite number of people available to move into housing. There are only a certain number of people who will want to move into a particular region, and that number will stop growing at some point.
Granted, you don't want to build too much and end up with a ghost town. There's a balance to be maintained, and I think housing should be affordable, not a race-to-the-bottom cheap as possible.
How much demand do you think CAN be induced? Colorado has 2.6M housing units for ~6M people. If Denver builds 20k units a year for the next 5 years, that would represent the entire state growing by 4% (230k people) off the back of one city alone. I guess that's not terribly unreasonable - if Denver was the only city in the country.
Except, it's not. Where would all of these extra people come from?
More to the point, Denver is already quite expensive. Where are you going to find another 230k people capable of paying even higher rents than folks do today?
Are there people who have been avoiding Denver because the rent is too high? I think of Denver as somewhere you go if you're sick of the cost of living on the coast.
> I think of Denver as somewhere you go if you're sick of the cost of living on the coast.
Denver hasn't been that place for more than a few decades. Heck, the whole rocky mountain region has never ever been a place for cheap housing. Western housing prices are high historically for reasons related to desirability. They never were as cheap as the midwest or deep south.
2 replies →
You could definitely do better if that's the only criteria.
Better to have good problems than to have bad problems.
Is you idea that people will be renting multiple units just for the fun of it? In large enough numbers to be impactful?
> It does. Twenty thousand units represent about 5% of Denver's housing stock [1]. Commit to adding this many units to the housing stock every year for the next 10 years and you'll have solved the housing crisis. (You'll probably need to bail out recent homebuyers, who will be permanently underwater, but that's a separate issue.)
"Committing to doing this every year" is VERY different than doing it in one particular year. Yes, that would solve it. But of course, 2022 was part of a very unusual cycle including a lot of migration and you should note the last line in the article:
> Meanwhile, the pipeline of new apartment buildings is drying up. The number of properties under construction is down by roughly one-third from the peak in 2023, the report found. That likely means fewer units coming available in the months ahead, potentially giving landlords room to start raising rents again.
> Commit to adding this many units to the housing stock every year for the next 10 years and you'll have solved the housing crisis.
That would be an incredible commitment, and not something which has happened. This burst of new rental property is already subsiding, with an expectation that rents will again raise next year. Moreso, it would be hard to get private organizations to commit to building such a massive glut of property knowing that they are tanking the market that would pay back their investment.
That is why this doesn't magically solve the housing crisis.
Why would we consider bailing out entities that are financially solvent? These homeowners may have an underwater investment, but they (presumably) can still pay the mortgage to get it paid off
I think Denver home prices have decreased by 4% since the peak in 2022.
I don't think anybody is going to be permanently underwater. Home prices changing should be a second order effect of building more apartments.
And what happens if all that new stock isn't needed?
Detroit?
Nope. Smaller more affordable homes would be a better solution. Most people who rent cant afford to buy, but rent is a worse deal long term.
This is only true for two reasons:
1. House prices have risen consistently for the past ~50 years. This is an anomaly (various theories why, my favourite is because women entered the workforce so the income per household increased and we spend as much as we can afford on housing). If/when house prices stop rising consistently then buying doesn't look much better than renting from a financial perspective.
2. Existing laws tend to favour the landlord over the tenant. In countries where this is not true (e.g. most of Europe) and the tenant is favoured, then renting is not so precarious and has lots of advantages.
I lived in rented accomodation in Berlin and it's a completely different experience from renting in the Anglosphere (UK or Australia for me, I don't know about the USA).
For single family homes square footage alone has a fairly modest impact on housing prices.
Land, driveway, number and quality of fixtures, electrical hookups, cabinets, countertops, doors, clearing land, water, sewage, etc can be nearly identical costs for a 1,000 sf or a 3,000sf home. Many things like wall insulation and heating demand increase sub linearly with square footage.
Which is why home builders so heavily favor large homes by historic standards. This is slightly less true of high rises, but making the building wider doesn’t require more elevators, internal hallways, etc.
A 1000 sqft, 3BR, 1 Bath, basic kitchen unit will be cheaper than a 3000 sqft 4BR, 2.5 Bath, fancy kitchen unit. Builders (and most everyone else involved in real estate) make a lot more money on the latter than the former, though.
5 replies →
It’s actually quite hard to definitively quantify if renting or owning is better in a given area/scenario.
Obviously the case near me where the mortgage payment on a house would be $2600/mo but the rent for the identical one next door is $2000 is going to swing heavily toward renting, but there’s more to it than just that.
Maintenance is huge and real and people just seem to ignore it on the “own” side, but 5-10% of the value of the house a year in maintenance isn’t unheard of.
> where the mortgage payment on a house would be $2600/mo but the rent for the identical one next door is $2000 is going to swing heavily toward renting
I think those figures point towards buying being favored, especially if the mortgage payment is PITI, but even if it's principal and interest only, I think buying is likely to be better in the long-term if the spread is that small.
Maintenance is not going to run 5% of the purchase price on average, except in the most extreme low-cost housing situations. A house that sold for ~$500K (as would be implied by a $2600 mortgage payment) is not going to cost $500K in maintenance over the next 20 years (as 5% would imply) and certainly not over the next 10 (as 10% would).
You may have an individual year that's over 10%, but that's a cashflow issue not an overall cost issue.
The advantage of renting is the flexibility, lack of commitment to a specific house or area, and the lack of need for a large upfront sum (in this example, renting might need $6K upfront [$2K of which is the first month's rent], while buying might need traditionally $100K to avoid PMI or ~$20K on an FHA first-time buyer mortgage and associated transaction costs).
> but 5-10% of the value of the house a year in maintenance isn’t unheard of.
I assure you I am not paying ~$30k in maintenance on my ~$400k house every year... that would be comical
4 replies →
> 5-10% of the value of the house a year in maintenance isn’t unheard of
That's actually pretty much unheard-of (unless you specifically bought a very cheap fixer-upper with the intent of remodeling).
I've owned current house for over 25 years and I have not spent 10% of its value in maintenance even if I add up everything over the 25+ years! Let alone every year!
Also, a lot of the loan payments go towards your own equity, whereas all of the rent goes to someone else's.
It is instructive to look at how we got expensive housing in the first place. Expensive housing comes from a surplus of people. How did we get all those people? By building more housing and having people breed there.
New housing is only a temporary salve and perpetuates a vicious cycle. The people who move into these new units will have more babies, because they have new habitat. These babies will grow up and eventually drive up housing prices. Even before then, people will move or emigrate into cheap housing and fill it up. Housing then becomes expensive again, only with more people filling up the earth: polluting the air, straining water supplies, clogging roads, uglifying neighborhoods with massive buildings, overrunning parks and trails.
Thankfully, expensive housing, in part, has reduced American baby making to 1.6 per woman, a sustainable rate. Unfortunately, because humans are living longer, the US population still continues to rise. The U.S. Census Bureau currently projects that the resident U.S. population will peak at nearly 370 million around the year 2080, before it gradually declines to about 366 million by 2100. If immortality is invented before 2080, the population may never go down, ever.
Meanwhile, the latest estimates put the current U.S. population (as of mid‑2025) at approximately 342 million. The population has increased roughly 4.5x since 1900. From building new housing.